It’s time to delve into the murky waters of the nexus
between money, central banks, governments, banks, and humankind. Most of
my thoughts are focused on the present and the future, rather than the
past, so that means there will be a certain amount of informed
speculation. It’s much more interesting to look forward and consider
where we are going (using current/recent events as a guide) rather than
be constantly looking backwards for a guide to the future. Everything is
subject to change at all times, so it’s best not to have a fixed view,
but to treat matters on the balance of probabilities having considered
all available evidence. So, some readers may need to cast aside any
existing biases and prejudices they may have around this rather meaty
subject, as the future is likely to make those biases irrelevant.
Where to begin? I’ll start by stating that I have seen plenty of evidence that money is and always has been debt, and that it simply evolved that way. The best anthropological evidence of this evolution is contained in the early sections of David Graeber’s book ‘Debt: the First 5,000 Years’.
(NB, I’ve not read the whole book, as Graeber’s solutions apparently do not differ much from those of Krugman, Piketty et al, and so are similarly interventionist, and hence flawed).
The barter economy is a myth. Mankind has always needed to account for its debts, whether to our rulers, to religions, to fellow producers, whatever the reason, we’ve needed a way to account for our debts. So various arbitrary items have served as money through the ages, some with intrinsic value, and some without. Knives, whales teeth, bracelets, horses, paper, gold, and even little electronic bits of data on a server: all have served as money at some time. Ultimately, all forms of money have always just been a record of what someone owes someone else. There’s nothing at all wrong with that in my opinion, it’s a natural method of dealing with the transactions that have always happened since man became civilised. It’s worth noting that these debts generally come with some interest charge to reflect the importance of time and risk of non-payment to the creditor, and again, I am supportive of interest charges to reflect the risk to the lender of non-repayment of his loan.
As far as I am aware, for many centuries (certainly back into the 1600s), money has been issued by the sovereign state (with just one recent exception). Whether that sovereign was a democracy, an empire, a monarchy or a totalitarian dictatorship, the sovereign has issued by decree the official money for its citizens. Of course, the sovereign gets a big advantage from this state of affairs, most obviously from the effects of seigniorage.
As central banks issue the notes and coins (and some of the electronic money too) we see the first example of the great monetary nexus. All of the central bank’s seigniorage profits flow back to the government in control of the sovereign state (with just one recent exception).
Apart from seigniorage, central banks and governments have always been tied at the hip for as long as central banks have existed (with one recent exception). Central banks were formed by Kings or governments to raise funds for wars and other items (such as to pay for line dancing parties for its employees).
Does Mr Carney agree with me? Here’s what he had to say:
‘Giving evidence to the Treasury Select Committee on financial stability, Mr Carney was asked his view on The Daily Telegraph’s interview with Jaime Caruana in which the head of BIS warned that the world economy is just as vulnerable now to financial crisis as it was in 2007. Mr Caruana had warned that investors were ignoring the risks of monetary tightening. In its annual report last month, BIS said the policy of “forward guidance”, adopted by the Bank of England and America’s Fed, was encouraging investors to take on more risk.
Mr Carney told the MPs that the BIS report was “interesting”. But he added “It’s a report that’s made in a vacuum though, the vacuum of Basel, a world where a central bank doesn’t have a mandate… a world where a central bank is not accountable to Parliament and through Parliament to the people, to achieve specific targets.”
While acknowledging the new CPI figures, Mr Carney pointed out that the Bank’s Monetary Policy Committee was not forecasting a return to the inflation target of 2pc for three years. “So in effect what the BIS would be recommending to the Bank of England would be to further extend the time over which it returned inflation to target beyond its forecast horizon, further than it ever has intended to do so, at a time when this economy has just re-attained its pre-crisis peak,” he said. “I’ll let you draw your own conclusions on the feasibility or advisability of that.”
It’s worth noting that the 2% CPI target also existed in the UK for the previous 5 years, have a look at the chart below, and I’ll let you draw your own conclusions on Mr Carney’s ‘independence’ , as well as his integrity.
I view the Federal Reserve as being the poodle of the US government, the Bank of England as being the poodle of the UK government, and the same with every other central bank in the world (with one group as the recent exception). The central banks have more recently taken to creating money from thin air to buy their own government’s debts, effectively printing money to fund the government when times are tough, a sign of desperation (on the part of the sovereigns) to be sure, in most instances. However, they seem unable to stop deflationary forces from spreading, so we will soon inhabit a world that recognises that monetarism is a myth, it simply doesn’t work (I’ll cover that in another post), and all that a central bank needs to do (and can deliver) is to maintain price stability.
So, we have to accept that central banks and their sovereign masters are happy to allow persistent inflation, and this is a relatively recent phenomenon, arriving early in the 20th century. Before that inflation and deflation came and went, and neither were predominant, as this very long term chart shows, generally prices were very steady over a very long period of time. But look at how it all changed early in the 20th century, as the world moved away from settling its national debts and allowing them to grow without limit. How can we NOT have had some deflation in the past 40 years? We’ve had globalisation, huge technological advances, and sliding demographics. It’s the sovereign/central bank nexus deliberately causing it, for their own benefit.
Of course, the world had been through hell for many years early in the last century, culminating in World War I. For some reason, at that moment in time, during the (forgotten) depression of the early 1920s, the great(?) nations of the world decided that they’d had enough of economic reality (living within their means) and they decided at a conference in Genoa in 1922 to change ‘the rules of the game’. For the first time, debts would not be settled (in gold) internationally, instead they could be settled (but not really) in paper gold promises-to-settle. I will probably look at why this change took place in another post, but my research to date indicates that the advent of democracy and socialism was a major influence, as well as American policy, designed to halt their depression and re-inflate the Europeans. The result was an immediate and massive inflation, engendered by the central banks via the banking system, applauded by the governments, and remembered these days as the Roaring 20s.
This image below is a section of a research paper by the Fed which explains how it all got a tad out of control within the central banking world, with reserves increasing by tenfold in this period, something like these past 7 years. Some of you may consider inflation to be a rise in prices of the things and services that we use and buy, but actually monetary inflation can (and does) often appear in financial markets first, as we saw during the 1920s. We all know how these things end however (even though most participants in the markets have no clue at the time). As I often repeat, certainly since the early 1920s, there is nothing much new in the world of money (with one notable recent exception).
So, to date (with one recent group as an exception), central banks have existed to help sovereigns meet the growing needs of the population, and make a bit of money to help said sovereign along the way. Is there anything inherently wrong with this set up? The only thing wrong with it is that continually (always) the people using the money take a hit (to varying degrees) as confidence erodes in the money being issued, and in the sovereign itself, and inflation gradually eats away at people’s real income levels and the value of their savings. (Also, eventually, it all collapses in a big heap, after serial bubble-blowing experiences, presenting its major flaw). However, it is fair to say that the population themselves would tend to be supportive of this nexus; certainly the majority would be, as they are in many ways reliant on the sovereign for their standard of living, especially in the past 100 years or so. Yes, your whole life has been lived within a debt bubble, did you know that? Well, it’s going to burst within the next 20 years, so do try to enjoy it while it lasts.
The desire these days is for government to take care of everything for us, from healthcare to education to pensions. I see plenty of evidence today, and through the past 60+ years that government does a pretty poor job of managing anything it attempts to manage, and of course when it comes to managing a sovereign economy made up of millions of individuals, each of them acting in isolation, within a global market place of many billions, and subject to the influences of nature, I roll my eyes at the futility of modern economic thinking and sovereign planning.
The longer-term (evolutionary) direction is away from this state of affairs though, and the breaking of the nexus is a strong move in that direction. You may agree that the end result for a government’s money is always likely to be the same, simply because the government is incompetent and biased in seeking to devalue its money and live beyond its means, and mankind and its economic interactions can’t be planned and controlled. Of course, you could rightly argue that many governments are simply a reflection of its voters, but that’s just evidence that pure democracy is likely to lead to poor outcomes, given humankind’s foibles and the desire of the less able to improve their lot at the expense of others, whilst always ignorant of the need to earn one’s standard of living via wealth creation. It’s ironic that democracy means that voters ultimately control what their governments provide, and if you’re accustomed to (or keen to escape from) abject poverty you are likely to vote for plenty of free stuff from the sovereign gravy train, whether that is at the expense of taxing those with more resources, or whether it means a continual increase in the national debt and ongoing inflation (at the expense of those with wealth). Most voters don’t really care about the debt, as long as they’re OK, and most voters don’t realise that their government is keen to see some inflation to maintain an appearance that all is well with the world, and of course to depreciate the real value of its own debts. Certainly, most voters never think about the longer-term implications of the debts accruing. The whole set-up is clearly flawed, and one day, in the not-too-distant future, we will see the final brutal denouement of these eternal inflations, a final day of reckoning. It will be shocking to behold, despite being inevitable since the 1920s, due to the laws of mathematics and market forces.
Until then (and maybe even afterwards) my fellow humans are unlikely to see where the problem lies, and therefore won’t see the solution as it unfolds before their eyes (even though it is helpfully described step-by-step by the architects of the evolution for all to see). Public opinion will continue to be informed by the left-leaning media, and of course by sovereigns themselves, especially as governments are pushed further and further into socialist policies by their voters.
So, if only there were a way of taking the central bank money creation power away from government and its people, or better still, if they decided to give up the money creation power voluntarily to a detached supra-sovereign system of some kind. Could that work? Keep reading. (If you’re thinking ‘But banks create most of our money via loans, yes, I know, and I’m coming on to this point next).
Let’s look at banks now, and where they fit into the nexus. Banks. You know, in the current monetary set-up, don’t you just hate banks? They make billions in profits when everything is on the way up, but when it all comes down they seem to be rescued by the taxpayer-funded sovereign. They break all sorts of laws (money-laundering and rigging markets for example), and they appear to do just about anything and everything in their quest for short-term profits. Yet, apart from relatively measly fines, and the odd individual criminal case, they seem to just get away with it. How do they do this? Well, it seems that their influence is clear, in that they spend a lot of money on politicians (both via donations and post-politics career opportunities).
Yes, the lawmakers like to help the banks. This is human nature of course, those seeking power (and its attached benefits) need money, to pay for campaigns and other incidentals. Banks can supply plenty of money. Those in power also need money to keep the government running, and the system (currently) relies on banks to buy huge amounts of all that government debt being issued. It’s mutually beneficial to all concerned in the current system.
It also works the other way of course, as many ex-bankers end up in government, pulling strings to help their former colleagues. This part of the nexus is clearly rigged heavily in the banks’ favour, but make no mistake that the sovereign is a clear beneficiary also, and given that the sovereign is following the path set by voters in democracies, then the citizens also benefit from this system, as it enables expansion of credit to households, and also enables expansion of government benefits and services via the funding of governments through bond issuance.
Here’s a link to a paper that examines the bank-sovereign nexus:
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/researchbulletin20en.pdf
Its conclusions are as follows:
‘The linkages between banks and sovereigns create a powerful amplification mechanism during fiscal crises. In Cooper and Nikolov (2013), banks are exposed to their sovereigns via their large government bond holdings and the sovereign is exposed to its banks through the need to provide bailout assistance during banking crises. As a result, sovereigns’ troubles can infect the banking system, amplifying the fragility of both banks and sovereigns. Popov and van Horen (2013) show that banks that are hit by sovereign debt write-downs significantly reduce lending, with potentially large negative implications for the real economy.’
The paper doesn’t touch on the shady stuff that also goes on, such as the revolving doors between certain governments, regulators and the bankers, but all of that nonsense just amplifies the advantages that the banks enjoy, reaping the rewards but never suffering the consequences of failure, at last not in the way ordinary business-people would suffer. It may be capitalism (with capital influencing those in power), but it’s certainly not a free and open market. So, the nexus between sovereigns and banks, I’m not really sure there is any beneficial result of the ties (unless you’re a fan of really big government of course), and ultimately the banks’ cavalier lending decisions end up causing bubbles and when the bubbles burst, the sovereign steps in and provides bailouts (or actually begins to extend the credit itself as banks withdraw, a sign that the nexus is beginning to unravel of its own accord?)
(the link above requires registration, which is free, but here are a few snippets:
‘Zoltan Pozsar — who will be at Camp Alphaville, so buy your ticket now! — has a fascinating new slide deck illustrating the changing landscape of US household debt, which, thankfully, is easier to read than his incredibly detailed map of the shadow banking system.
While the total stock of household obligations is only slightly lower than it was at the peak in 2008, the composition of the lenders has changed dramatically. The government, which for our purposes includes Fannie and Freddie as well as the Federal Reserve, has become far more important, while so-called “shadow banks”, private-label securitisation, and foreigners have all become less important. On the whole, this is probably good for financial stability.’
‘In terms of ownership, about a quarter ($3 trillion) of the total stock of debt owed by American households is held either directly by the government or central bank. (This slightly understates the role of government as creditor to the household sector since the $1 trillion “other” category includes mortgages retained by Fannie and Freddie, as well as consumer loans and mortgages made by credit unions). What’s changed since the crisis?
For starters, the government has become much more important because it is the only sector meaningfully boosting credit provision to American households. The Fed bought about $1.7 trillion worth of agency MBS, while the Department of Education started making (and retaining) student loans in size. By contrast, “shadow” lending has contracted by about a third (from $3 trillion to $2 trillion) while domestic “real money” holdings of household debt have collapsed by about half (from roughly $4 trillion to $2 trillion). Traditional bank loans retained on the balance sheet are up since the crisis, but not by much.
These trends aren’t purely a function of the government having effectively stepped in as a lender of last resort to the household sector during the worst of the downturn. Even if you start the clock in mid-2012, when the total stock of household debt hit bottom and began growing again, it’s still the case that the bulk of new household borrowing has been financed one way or another by the government. Unleveraged investors, foreign banks, and the “shadow” system all continued to reduce their exposure during this period as well.’
Join me in cringing at the conclusion that government taking over the role of lender of last resort to the population is ‘good for financial stability’. Another statist writer, they’re everywhere these days.
Once again, it’s a significant portion of the other member of this nexus that gets hit as banks are bailed out: the poor old taxpayer, as his taxes rise, and his currency takes a hit (to varying degrees). Anyone with savings, pensions, or an earned income suffers, whilst those relying on the sovereign for work or welfare are protected to a large degree. Some blame capitalism for this state of affairs. I prefer to be clear: the current set up is very far removed from a free, fair and open market, and whilst capitalism does not mean the same as ‘free, fair and open markets’, big banks are giving capitalism a bad name.
If there is a benefit from the nexus as described so far, it has been to enable a huge artificial increase in the standard of living of the developed world (and to a certain extent the whole world) as the temporary effects of hundreds of trillions of unconstrained debt spending feed through to the masses. It’s very liberating to realise that virtually everyone alive today has lived within a freakishly massive bubble that started in 1922. But hardly anyone realises it. They will realise it eventually as the final reckoning lies ahead, maybe as the next economic downturn unfolds, or maybe at some point further down the line.
If only, we wish, there was some way to break the nexus between banks and sovereigns, so that bailouts were not available, so that banks were more careful in buying government debt (because it’s not risk-free you know).
If only the normal rules of the market were applied to banks (if you mess up: tough luck, bye bye). If only mankind was clever enough to devise some way to solve these problems.
Jumping back to money itself, and its place in the nexus. What do we really want from money? In this instance, for the sake of clarity, I am going to refer to a cardboard box of paper notes carefully hidden under one’s bed. Real physical paper money.
Speaking for myself, I want to be able to spend that money whenever I choose in my home country (plus other countries if possible, that would be a bonus), so it needs to facilitate the exchange of goods and services. Ideally, it would be handy if it were available in nice round amounts, so that I could add it all up easily and without needing a calculator. And ideally, I’d want to know that it would hold its value over time, especially over what I would term the ‘short/medium term’ of up to 5 years. That isn’t a long list of requirements for money to work for me, and it’s not really an especially demanding list of requirements. Is it? I can read your mind, you’re thinking ‘but money never holds its value’ or ‘there’s always inflation and there always will be’. These are understandable thoughts, as they are based on your experience of money to date, and the experience of nearly everyone that has ever used money on our planet. (Although we have experienced long periods in the past where money not only held its value, it actually gained in value in real terms due to the impact of deflation on prices).
So far, sadly, in the current system established in 1922, money has failed to perform one of its basic tasks: to maintain its value. In many cases of course, money has done the precise opposite, and has lost all of its value, via a collapse in confidence in the issuer of the money. Bear in mind that all issuers to date have been sovereign states (and their central banks) with their own money (with one recent group as an exception). So, ultimately, the collapse of money’s value is a collapse in confidence in the sovereign itself. Maybe because the sovereign has overspent, and kept overspending past any sort of reasonable limits, because they had the means to do so, thanks to the generous central bank over the road, and the banks that grease it all along the way. It doesn’t matter what sort of money we’ve tried in the past or right now (with one recent exception), the sovereign has always found a way to ruin it eventually. Human nature? A poor system? Natural cycles? Inevitability? Yes to all of these I think.
So, the pessimists amongst you will already have concluded that this is the way of the monetary world, we are doomed to repeat history over and over again, and the only way to escape the madness is to embrace it as inevitable and find some way to hedge against the effects of the nexus. This is not the case. The passage of time will reveal much, perhaps even to those with their minds made up already, but something radically different is being attempted, right now.
The final link in the nexus of money is of course the citizens who use it daily to run their own affairs, people who earn it, people who borrow it, people who save it (via banks or into various investment assets), and people who generally rely on money for one reason or another to safeguard their financial welfare now and in the future.
Since the end of the second world war, the developed world has moved further and further into debt in order to provide many of the welfare benefits that its citizens now take for granted. The population is so accustomed to the largesse of this sovereign gravy train that they cannot conceive of it shrinking. Some of them may believe that welfare for the indolent should be reduced, but tell them that their state pensions will be similarly cut and you’ll lose their vote at the next election. As demographic trends mean that ageing voters already outnumber the younger generation, it would seem a safe bet that voters will not be voting for reductions in government budgets any time soon. So, within the nexus, voters are driving government budgets further and further into the red. Even in countries where voting is not required, or is a sham, sovereigns are still driven along the same road by the knowledge that their population is accustomed to a certain lifestyle, and so it needs to be maintained, or revolutionary thoughts may arise. Politicians don’t need elections to realise this obvious fact. Voters are ignorant of the central bank-sovereign nexus as described in this post, and also oblivious to the fact that as recently as the 1970s many major currencies and sovereigns were in deep monetary trouble, with inflation/confidence issues running out of control. No voters (or politicians or central bankers) see that being repeated in the future, they are confident in their sovereign state and the money they use every day, even as they see their real incomes dwindle in recent years. The average man or woman doesn’t understand what causes inflation, or the influence of these nexus connections in ensuring it is guaranteed (and even targetted) in the current system.
I’m not really sure what the uninformed person thinks about banks these days if I’m honest. Maybe they distrust them, maybe dislike the taxpayer-funded bailouts they received, and begrudge the huge salaries and bonuses they imagine the bankers receive? But the levels of debt held at household level in most of the developed world indicate that the people are quite happy to borrow from banks to fund consumption, as well as for investment and home purchase. So, a necessary evil; that might be the view of the man on the street? Would the citizens of the developed world have been happy to see many major banks go bust in the credit crunch crisis? I think that would depend on how each of them was affected personally. If they didn’t lose any money themselves, I think most people would have been happy to see a few banks go under. But those people were probably ignorant of how much the banks support their sovereign’s own borrowing requirements, and therefore how they would have been affected by bank failures. My conclusion is that the developed world’s population are mostly totally ignorant about these issues, and so the other elements of the nexus can continue their insane dance for as long as it all holds together, whilst throwing the masses a narrative that at least gives the appearance that naughty bankers will be punished (with one notable recent exception).
One final point before I move on to the changes that are afoot that have the potential to shatter this nexus for good (and for the better). Inflation is a deliberate feature of the nexus, pushed into the system by ever-increasing debt bubbles which are blown by the banks and sovereigns to suit their own agendas (short-term profits and larger governments) whilst being welcomed by the masses, as they love to borrow cheap money for items that would otherwise be unaffordable. There is however no reason whatsoever why inflation needs to be a permanent feature of our monetary system, once the nexus is broken, and indeed inflation and deflation were both features of sovereign money before central banks were created. If you consider the last 30-40 years, and the huge technological advancements we have seen, as well as the impact of globalisation on corporate cost structures, you may wonder how on earth we haven’t seen very regular beneficial periods of falling prices in all goods and services. Instead, we have seen deflation in some areas (such as computer technologies), and inflation in others (such as food and energy). This is accepted as ‘normal’ by most, but there is no need for it. A little bit of inflation every year may appear to be insignificant, and you may think there’s really no need for the status quo to change in that regard (as long as you yourself can find a way to hedge against it). But that attitude ignores the pernicious effect inflation has over the longer-term (10 years+), and how it forces people into the arms of the financial industry in seeking to protect their wealth and their future income (pension funds) from the effects of inflation. It also ignores the simple mathematical fact that any system built upon ever-increasing debt bubbles simply can’t and won’t be sustainable forever; it will ultimately collapse in a heap. Add to that the detrimental effects of ever-larger governments (non-productive, absorbing the wealth and incomes of its citizens, the ultimate parasite), not to mention their capacity to wage wars when it suits them, and I believe that those who support (or accept with a shrug) the post-1922 system and its continuation are intellectually very lazy.
Thankfully, change is already upon us, although you may not have noticed it yet. If you follow the financial world at all, you will have seen examples of the nexus being broken, but perhaps you don’t grasp the implications, or realise that what you noticed wasn’t just a one-off, it was actually a signal of a wholesale changing of the rules, and the destruction of the nexus itself, taking us back to a world where economic reality is based upon the principles of free, fair and open markets, and their application to ALL actors within an economy, including banks, central banks, sovereigns and the people themselves. But I recognise that we’re not headed for an anarcho-capitalist system, with zero government, no welfare, and everything left to individuals to decide locally. No, we are headed for a system where voters will decide exactly what they are prepared to pay their governments to deliver, based upon taxation and a relatively modest amount of borrowing, priced at a rate of interest set by the market. Finally, a system where governments won’t be able to levy the hidden inflation tax on everyone, as there will no mechanism to do so, as the nexus connections will have been (and are in the process of being currently) severed.
The changes ahead will be dramatic and painful (in the short term) for many. But a huge leap forward is being attempted, and I expect it to be successful.
Where to begin? I’ll start by stating that I have seen plenty of evidence that money is and always has been debt, and that it simply evolved that way. The best anthropological evidence of this evolution is contained in the early sections of David Graeber’s book ‘Debt: the First 5,000 Years’.
(NB, I’ve not read the whole book, as Graeber’s solutions apparently do not differ much from those of Krugman, Piketty et al, and so are similarly interventionist, and hence flawed).
The barter economy is a myth. Mankind has always needed to account for its debts, whether to our rulers, to religions, to fellow producers, whatever the reason, we’ve needed a way to account for our debts. So various arbitrary items have served as money through the ages, some with intrinsic value, and some without. Knives, whales teeth, bracelets, horses, paper, gold, and even little electronic bits of data on a server: all have served as money at some time. Ultimately, all forms of money have always just been a record of what someone owes someone else. There’s nothing at all wrong with that in my opinion, it’s a natural method of dealing with the transactions that have always happened since man became civilised. It’s worth noting that these debts generally come with some interest charge to reflect the importance of time and risk of non-payment to the creditor, and again, I am supportive of interest charges to reflect the risk to the lender of non-repayment of his loan.
As far as I am aware, for many centuries (certainly back into the 1600s), money has been issued by the sovereign state (with just one recent exception). Whether that sovereign was a democracy, an empire, a monarchy or a totalitarian dictatorship, the sovereign has issued by decree the official money for its citizens. Of course, the sovereign gets a big advantage from this state of affairs, most obviously from the effects of seigniorage.
As central banks issue the notes and coins (and some of the electronic money too) we see the first example of the great monetary nexus. All of the central bank’s seigniorage profits flow back to the government in control of the sovereign state (with just one recent exception).
Apart from seigniorage, central banks and governments have always been tied at the hip for as long as central banks have existed (with one recent exception). Central banks were formed by Kings or governments to raise funds for wars and other items (such as to pay for line dancing parties for its employees).
Central banks have continued to act as
fund-raisers for sovereigns ever since. But sometimes it’s been a
two-way street, and the central bank itself has needed a government
bailout, or has simply been abolished, along with the currency itself,
lost to history, as both the currency and the government itself
collapse. It’s not really been a particularly strong track record for
this pair within the nexus.
In modern times, central banks are generally thought of as
independent from the state, but my view is that the reality is the
opposite. This article touches on that subject:‘Giving evidence to the Treasury Select Committee on financial stability, Mr Carney was asked his view on The Daily Telegraph’s interview with Jaime Caruana in which the head of BIS warned that the world economy is just as vulnerable now to financial crisis as it was in 2007. Mr Caruana had warned that investors were ignoring the risks of monetary tightening. In its annual report last month, BIS said the policy of “forward guidance”, adopted by the Bank of England and America’s Fed, was encouraging investors to take on more risk.
Mr Carney told the MPs that the BIS report was “interesting”. But he added “It’s a report that’s made in a vacuum though, the vacuum of Basel, a world where a central bank doesn’t have a mandate… a world where a central bank is not accountable to Parliament and through Parliament to the people, to achieve specific targets.”
While acknowledging the new CPI figures, Mr Carney pointed out that the Bank’s Monetary Policy Committee was not forecasting a return to the inflation target of 2pc for three years. “So in effect what the BIS would be recommending to the Bank of England would be to further extend the time over which it returned inflation to target beyond its forecast horizon, further than it ever has intended to do so, at a time when this economy has just re-attained its pre-crisis peak,” he said. “I’ll let you draw your own conclusions on the feasibility or advisability of that.”
It’s worth noting that the 2% CPI target also existed in the UK for the previous 5 years, have a look at the chart below, and I’ll let you draw your own conclusions on Mr Carney’s ‘independence’ , as well as his integrity.
I view the Federal Reserve as being the poodle of the US government, the Bank of England as being the poodle of the UK government, and the same with every other central bank in the world (with one group as the recent exception). The central banks have more recently taken to creating money from thin air to buy their own government’s debts, effectively printing money to fund the government when times are tough, a sign of desperation (on the part of the sovereigns) to be sure, in most instances. However, they seem unable to stop deflationary forces from spreading, so we will soon inhabit a world that recognises that monetarism is a myth, it simply doesn’t work (I’ll cover that in another post), and all that a central bank needs to do (and can deliver) is to maintain price stability.
So, we have to accept that central banks and their sovereign masters are happy to allow persistent inflation, and this is a relatively recent phenomenon, arriving early in the 20th century. Before that inflation and deflation came and went, and neither were predominant, as this very long term chart shows, generally prices were very steady over a very long period of time. But look at how it all changed early in the 20th century, as the world moved away from settling its national debts and allowing them to grow without limit. How can we NOT have had some deflation in the past 40 years? We’ve had globalisation, huge technological advances, and sliding demographics. It’s the sovereign/central bank nexus deliberately causing it, for their own benefit.
Of course, the world had been through hell for many years early in the last century, culminating in World War I. For some reason, at that moment in time, during the (forgotten) depression of the early 1920s, the great(?) nations of the world decided that they’d had enough of economic reality (living within their means) and they decided at a conference in Genoa in 1922 to change ‘the rules of the game’. For the first time, debts would not be settled (in gold) internationally, instead they could be settled (but not really) in paper gold promises-to-settle. I will probably look at why this change took place in another post, but my research to date indicates that the advent of democracy and socialism was a major influence, as well as American policy, designed to halt their depression and re-inflate the Europeans. The result was an immediate and massive inflation, engendered by the central banks via the banking system, applauded by the governments, and remembered these days as the Roaring 20s.
This image below is a section of a research paper by the Fed which explains how it all got a tad out of control within the central banking world, with reserves increasing by tenfold in this period, something like these past 7 years. Some of you may consider inflation to be a rise in prices of the things and services that we use and buy, but actually monetary inflation can (and does) often appear in financial markets first, as we saw during the 1920s. We all know how these things end however (even though most participants in the markets have no clue at the time). As I often repeat, certainly since the early 1920s, there is nothing much new in the world of money (with one notable recent exception).
So, to date (with one recent group as an exception), central banks have existed to help sovereigns meet the growing needs of the population, and make a bit of money to help said sovereign along the way. Is there anything inherently wrong with this set up? The only thing wrong with it is that continually (always) the people using the money take a hit (to varying degrees) as confidence erodes in the money being issued, and in the sovereign itself, and inflation gradually eats away at people’s real income levels and the value of their savings. (Also, eventually, it all collapses in a big heap, after serial bubble-blowing experiences, presenting its major flaw). However, it is fair to say that the population themselves would tend to be supportive of this nexus; certainly the majority would be, as they are in many ways reliant on the sovereign for their standard of living, especially in the past 100 years or so. Yes, your whole life has been lived within a debt bubble, did you know that? Well, it’s going to burst within the next 20 years, so do try to enjoy it while it lasts.
The desire these days is for government to take care of everything for us, from healthcare to education to pensions. I see plenty of evidence today, and through the past 60+ years that government does a pretty poor job of managing anything it attempts to manage, and of course when it comes to managing a sovereign economy made up of millions of individuals, each of them acting in isolation, within a global market place of many billions, and subject to the influences of nature, I roll my eyes at the futility of modern economic thinking and sovereign planning.
The longer-term (evolutionary) direction is away from this state of affairs though, and the breaking of the nexus is a strong move in that direction. You may agree that the end result for a government’s money is always likely to be the same, simply because the government is incompetent and biased in seeking to devalue its money and live beyond its means, and mankind and its economic interactions can’t be planned and controlled. Of course, you could rightly argue that many governments are simply a reflection of its voters, but that’s just evidence that pure democracy is likely to lead to poor outcomes, given humankind’s foibles and the desire of the less able to improve their lot at the expense of others, whilst always ignorant of the need to earn one’s standard of living via wealth creation. It’s ironic that democracy means that voters ultimately control what their governments provide, and if you’re accustomed to (or keen to escape from) abject poverty you are likely to vote for plenty of free stuff from the sovereign gravy train, whether that is at the expense of taxing those with more resources, or whether it means a continual increase in the national debt and ongoing inflation (at the expense of those with wealth). Most voters don’t really care about the debt, as long as they’re OK, and most voters don’t realise that their government is keen to see some inflation to maintain an appearance that all is well with the world, and of course to depreciate the real value of its own debts. Certainly, most voters never think about the longer-term implications of the debts accruing. The whole set-up is clearly flawed, and one day, in the not-too-distant future, we will see the final brutal denouement of these eternal inflations, a final day of reckoning. It will be shocking to behold, despite being inevitable since the 1920s, due to the laws of mathematics and market forces.
Until then (and maybe even afterwards) my fellow humans are unlikely to see where the problem lies, and therefore won’t see the solution as it unfolds before their eyes (even though it is helpfully described step-by-step by the architects of the evolution for all to see). Public opinion will continue to be informed by the left-leaning media, and of course by sovereigns themselves, especially as governments are pushed further and further into socialist policies by their voters.
So, if only there were a way of taking the central bank money creation power away from government and its people, or better still, if they decided to give up the money creation power voluntarily to a detached supra-sovereign system of some kind. Could that work? Keep reading. (If you’re thinking ‘But banks create most of our money via loans, yes, I know, and I’m coming on to this point next).
Let’s look at banks now, and where they fit into the nexus. Banks. You know, in the current monetary set-up, don’t you just hate banks? They make billions in profits when everything is on the way up, but when it all comes down they seem to be rescued by the taxpayer-funded sovereign. They break all sorts of laws (money-laundering and rigging markets for example), and they appear to do just about anything and everything in their quest for short-term profits. Yet, apart from relatively measly fines, and the odd individual criminal case, they seem to just get away with it. How do they do this? Well, it seems that their influence is clear, in that they spend a lot of money on politicians (both via donations and post-politics career opportunities).
Yes, the lawmakers like to help the banks. This is human nature of course, those seeking power (and its attached benefits) need money, to pay for campaigns and other incidentals. Banks can supply plenty of money. Those in power also need money to keep the government running, and the system (currently) relies on banks to buy huge amounts of all that government debt being issued. It’s mutually beneficial to all concerned in the current system.
It also works the other way of course, as many ex-bankers end up in government, pulling strings to help their former colleagues. This part of the nexus is clearly rigged heavily in the banks’ favour, but make no mistake that the sovereign is a clear beneficiary also, and given that the sovereign is following the path set by voters in democracies, then the citizens also benefit from this system, as it enables expansion of credit to households, and also enables expansion of government benefits and services via the funding of governments through bond issuance.
Here’s a link to a paper that examines the bank-sovereign nexus:
https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/other/researchbulletin20en.pdf
Its conclusions are as follows:
‘The linkages between banks and sovereigns create a powerful amplification mechanism during fiscal crises. In Cooper and Nikolov (2013), banks are exposed to their sovereigns via their large government bond holdings and the sovereign is exposed to its banks through the need to provide bailout assistance during banking crises. As a result, sovereigns’ troubles can infect the banking system, amplifying the fragility of both banks and sovereigns. Popov and van Horen (2013) show that banks that are hit by sovereign debt write-downs significantly reduce lending, with potentially large negative implications for the real economy.’
The paper doesn’t touch on the shady stuff that also goes on, such as the revolving doors between certain governments, regulators and the bankers, but all of that nonsense just amplifies the advantages that the banks enjoy, reaping the rewards but never suffering the consequences of failure, at last not in the way ordinary business-people would suffer. It may be capitalism (with capital influencing those in power), but it’s certainly not a free and open market. So, the nexus between sovereigns and banks, I’m not really sure there is any beneficial result of the ties (unless you’re a fan of really big government of course), and ultimately the banks’ cavalier lending decisions end up causing bubbles and when the bubbles burst, the sovereign steps in and provides bailouts (or actually begins to extend the credit itself as banks withdraw, a sign that the nexus is beginning to unravel of its own accord?)
(the link above requires registration, which is free, but here are a few snippets:
‘Zoltan Pozsar — who will be at Camp Alphaville, so buy your ticket now! — has a fascinating new slide deck illustrating the changing landscape of US household debt, which, thankfully, is easier to read than his incredibly detailed map of the shadow banking system.
While the total stock of household obligations is only slightly lower than it was at the peak in 2008, the composition of the lenders has changed dramatically. The government, which for our purposes includes Fannie and Freddie as well as the Federal Reserve, has become far more important, while so-called “shadow banks”, private-label securitisation, and foreigners have all become less important. On the whole, this is probably good for financial stability.’
‘In terms of ownership, about a quarter ($3 trillion) of the total stock of debt owed by American households is held either directly by the government or central bank. (This slightly understates the role of government as creditor to the household sector since the $1 trillion “other” category includes mortgages retained by Fannie and Freddie, as well as consumer loans and mortgages made by credit unions). What’s changed since the crisis?
For starters, the government has become much more important because it is the only sector meaningfully boosting credit provision to American households. The Fed bought about $1.7 trillion worth of agency MBS, while the Department of Education started making (and retaining) student loans in size. By contrast, “shadow” lending has contracted by about a third (from $3 trillion to $2 trillion) while domestic “real money” holdings of household debt have collapsed by about half (from roughly $4 trillion to $2 trillion). Traditional bank loans retained on the balance sheet are up since the crisis, but not by much.
These trends aren’t purely a function of the government having effectively stepped in as a lender of last resort to the household sector during the worst of the downturn. Even if you start the clock in mid-2012, when the total stock of household debt hit bottom and began growing again, it’s still the case that the bulk of new household borrowing has been financed one way or another by the government. Unleveraged investors, foreign banks, and the “shadow” system all continued to reduce their exposure during this period as well.’
Join me in cringing at the conclusion that government taking over the role of lender of last resort to the population is ‘good for financial stability’. Another statist writer, they’re everywhere these days.
Once again, it’s a significant portion of the other member of this nexus that gets hit as banks are bailed out: the poor old taxpayer, as his taxes rise, and his currency takes a hit (to varying degrees). Anyone with savings, pensions, or an earned income suffers, whilst those relying on the sovereign for work or welfare are protected to a large degree. Some blame capitalism for this state of affairs. I prefer to be clear: the current set up is very far removed from a free, fair and open market, and whilst capitalism does not mean the same as ‘free, fair and open markets’, big banks are giving capitalism a bad name.
If there is a benefit from the nexus as described so far, it has been to enable a huge artificial increase in the standard of living of the developed world (and to a certain extent the whole world) as the temporary effects of hundreds of trillions of unconstrained debt spending feed through to the masses. It’s very liberating to realise that virtually everyone alive today has lived within a freakishly massive bubble that started in 1922. But hardly anyone realises it. They will realise it eventually as the final reckoning lies ahead, maybe as the next economic downturn unfolds, or maybe at some point further down the line.
If only, we wish, there was some way to break the nexus between banks and sovereigns, so that bailouts were not available, so that banks were more careful in buying government debt (because it’s not risk-free you know).
If only the normal rules of the market were applied to banks (if you mess up: tough luck, bye bye). If only mankind was clever enough to devise some way to solve these problems.
Jumping back to money itself, and its place in the nexus. What do we really want from money? In this instance, for the sake of clarity, I am going to refer to a cardboard box of paper notes carefully hidden under one’s bed. Real physical paper money.
Speaking for myself, I want to be able to spend that money whenever I choose in my home country (plus other countries if possible, that would be a bonus), so it needs to facilitate the exchange of goods and services. Ideally, it would be handy if it were available in nice round amounts, so that I could add it all up easily and without needing a calculator. And ideally, I’d want to know that it would hold its value over time, especially over what I would term the ‘short/medium term’ of up to 5 years. That isn’t a long list of requirements for money to work for me, and it’s not really an especially demanding list of requirements. Is it? I can read your mind, you’re thinking ‘but money never holds its value’ or ‘there’s always inflation and there always will be’. These are understandable thoughts, as they are based on your experience of money to date, and the experience of nearly everyone that has ever used money on our planet. (Although we have experienced long periods in the past where money not only held its value, it actually gained in value in real terms due to the impact of deflation on prices).
So far, sadly, in the current system established in 1922, money has failed to perform one of its basic tasks: to maintain its value. In many cases of course, money has done the precise opposite, and has lost all of its value, via a collapse in confidence in the issuer of the money. Bear in mind that all issuers to date have been sovereign states (and their central banks) with their own money (with one recent group as an exception). So, ultimately, the collapse of money’s value is a collapse in confidence in the sovereign itself. Maybe because the sovereign has overspent, and kept overspending past any sort of reasonable limits, because they had the means to do so, thanks to the generous central bank over the road, and the banks that grease it all along the way. It doesn’t matter what sort of money we’ve tried in the past or right now (with one recent exception), the sovereign has always found a way to ruin it eventually. Human nature? A poor system? Natural cycles? Inevitability? Yes to all of these I think.
So, the pessimists amongst you will already have concluded that this is the way of the monetary world, we are doomed to repeat history over and over again, and the only way to escape the madness is to embrace it as inevitable and find some way to hedge against the effects of the nexus. This is not the case. The passage of time will reveal much, perhaps even to those with their minds made up already, but something radically different is being attempted, right now.
The final link in the nexus of money is of course the citizens who use it daily to run their own affairs, people who earn it, people who borrow it, people who save it (via banks or into various investment assets), and people who generally rely on money for one reason or another to safeguard their financial welfare now and in the future.
Since the end of the second world war, the developed world has moved further and further into debt in order to provide many of the welfare benefits that its citizens now take for granted. The population is so accustomed to the largesse of this sovereign gravy train that they cannot conceive of it shrinking. Some of them may believe that welfare for the indolent should be reduced, but tell them that their state pensions will be similarly cut and you’ll lose their vote at the next election. As demographic trends mean that ageing voters already outnumber the younger generation, it would seem a safe bet that voters will not be voting for reductions in government budgets any time soon. So, within the nexus, voters are driving government budgets further and further into the red. Even in countries where voting is not required, or is a sham, sovereigns are still driven along the same road by the knowledge that their population is accustomed to a certain lifestyle, and so it needs to be maintained, or revolutionary thoughts may arise. Politicians don’t need elections to realise this obvious fact. Voters are ignorant of the central bank-sovereign nexus as described in this post, and also oblivious to the fact that as recently as the 1970s many major currencies and sovereigns were in deep monetary trouble, with inflation/confidence issues running out of control. No voters (or politicians or central bankers) see that being repeated in the future, they are confident in their sovereign state and the money they use every day, even as they see their real incomes dwindle in recent years. The average man or woman doesn’t understand what causes inflation, or the influence of these nexus connections in ensuring it is guaranteed (and even targetted) in the current system.
I’m not really sure what the uninformed person thinks about banks these days if I’m honest. Maybe they distrust them, maybe dislike the taxpayer-funded bailouts they received, and begrudge the huge salaries and bonuses they imagine the bankers receive? But the levels of debt held at household level in most of the developed world indicate that the people are quite happy to borrow from banks to fund consumption, as well as for investment and home purchase. So, a necessary evil; that might be the view of the man on the street? Would the citizens of the developed world have been happy to see many major banks go bust in the credit crunch crisis? I think that would depend on how each of them was affected personally. If they didn’t lose any money themselves, I think most people would have been happy to see a few banks go under. But those people were probably ignorant of how much the banks support their sovereign’s own borrowing requirements, and therefore how they would have been affected by bank failures. My conclusion is that the developed world’s population are mostly totally ignorant about these issues, and so the other elements of the nexus can continue their insane dance for as long as it all holds together, whilst throwing the masses a narrative that at least gives the appearance that naughty bankers will be punished (with one notable recent exception).
One final point before I move on to the changes that are afoot that have the potential to shatter this nexus for good (and for the better). Inflation is a deliberate feature of the nexus, pushed into the system by ever-increasing debt bubbles which are blown by the banks and sovereigns to suit their own agendas (short-term profits and larger governments) whilst being welcomed by the masses, as they love to borrow cheap money for items that would otherwise be unaffordable. There is however no reason whatsoever why inflation needs to be a permanent feature of our monetary system, once the nexus is broken, and indeed inflation and deflation were both features of sovereign money before central banks were created. If you consider the last 30-40 years, and the huge technological advancements we have seen, as well as the impact of globalisation on corporate cost structures, you may wonder how on earth we haven’t seen very regular beneficial periods of falling prices in all goods and services. Instead, we have seen deflation in some areas (such as computer technologies), and inflation in others (such as food and energy). This is accepted as ‘normal’ by most, but there is no need for it. A little bit of inflation every year may appear to be insignificant, and you may think there’s really no need for the status quo to change in that regard (as long as you yourself can find a way to hedge against it). But that attitude ignores the pernicious effect inflation has over the longer-term (10 years+), and how it forces people into the arms of the financial industry in seeking to protect their wealth and their future income (pension funds) from the effects of inflation. It also ignores the simple mathematical fact that any system built upon ever-increasing debt bubbles simply can’t and won’t be sustainable forever; it will ultimately collapse in a heap. Add to that the detrimental effects of ever-larger governments (non-productive, absorbing the wealth and incomes of its citizens, the ultimate parasite), not to mention their capacity to wage wars when it suits them, and I believe that those who support (or accept with a shrug) the post-1922 system and its continuation are intellectually very lazy.
Thankfully, change is already upon us, although you may not have noticed it yet. If you follow the financial world at all, you will have seen examples of the nexus being broken, but perhaps you don’t grasp the implications, or realise that what you noticed wasn’t just a one-off, it was actually a signal of a wholesale changing of the rules, and the destruction of the nexus itself, taking us back to a world where economic reality is based upon the principles of free, fair and open markets, and their application to ALL actors within an economy, including banks, central banks, sovereigns and the people themselves. But I recognise that we’re not headed for an anarcho-capitalist system, with zero government, no welfare, and everything left to individuals to decide locally. No, we are headed for a system where voters will decide exactly what they are prepared to pay their governments to deliver, based upon taxation and a relatively modest amount of borrowing, priced at a rate of interest set by the market. Finally, a system where governments won’t be able to levy the hidden inflation tax on everyone, as there will no mechanism to do so, as the nexus connections will have been (and are in the process of being currently) severed.
The changes ahead will be dramatic and painful (in the short term) for many. But a huge leap forward is being attempted, and I expect it to be successful.
18 comments:
One explanation as to why the "execessive" debts haven't resulted in a collapse is that we have innovation cycles where a breakthrough in technology/productivity occurs, making the payment back of those promises (that appeared to observers to be unable to be paid) in real wealth possible and the cycle continues.
For example, if I have an orchard that produces 10,000 apples a year but over time I have issued "apple notes" for 15,000, then an observer would say it will fail next year when people come to redeem their notes for real apples. But if I discover the benefit of compost and netting my orchard and my yield increases to 15,000, then no collapse.
Accepting this idea does not mean accepting that the system will not collapse, but that it may take longer than first thought. In this context I find this article https://dizzynomics.wordpress.com/2015/08/05/breaking-the-wheel/ particularly interesting and the observation that "the period between each disruptive cycle is getting shorter. At the same time the scale of the disruption is intensifying — something which must continue to happen if our growing and scaling system is to avoid collapse".
The question is how many more cycles do we have to go? I'm not so sure it will happen 2015.75 or longwave or whatever.
@Gary,
nice post, waiting for the next one :)
@Bron,
The point is, who is holding and accepting the debt.
In your apple example: Let's assume that for some reason I am the only super rich person managed to aquire holding all of those (over issued) 15000 apple notes. Now, I actually dont really like apples, only buying one per month, than what? Even if your orchard only produces real 3 apples per month, no reason that something "breaks".
Greets, AD
Hello Bron.
One could argue that the excessive debts have resulted in collapse 3 times already: the 1930s, the 1970s, and 2008-09. Each time it's been different, but it's slowly reaching a point where a rescue won't be desirable, as the system itself has become a hindrance. The world now appears ready to move on, from China to Russia to Saudi Arabia to Europe. America may try to cling to its privilege, and may go down fighting (within its own borders only we hope), but we're moving on within 20 years. But I agree, it all takes what seems like a very long time and technology has certainly helped keep inflationary pressures at bay.
Thanks AD, yes I don't doubt that Part 2 will interest you, knowing your love of all things European!
Yes Gary,
cant wait to beat down your hero Super Mario aka "let's print baby, whatever it takes". Or my favorite Mr. Schäuble, "this is the very final rescue package, really definitely, (at least until the next one...)".
Greets, AD
Hi Gary
Thanks very much for this thought provoking article.
You've clearly laid out the 'benefits' that each group within the nexus obtains from the current system....and that kept me thinking which 'group' will benefit from the 'new' system that you are hinting at. It surely isn't being done for the 'benefit of all humanity'!! Of that we can be certain.
I'll await Part 2 for the answer.
Purvez
Do you have a newsletter? Or just a blogger.. Thanks in advance
Hello. I write here also: http://www.monetaryperspectives.com/
No newsletter though sorry.
Just some funny stuff in the meantime:
Received lately some SPAM mail from my gold dealer, first after selling Asterix gold coins, followed by a coloured StarTrek series (PerthMint, what's wrong with you? OMG!!111) and now they wanna sell me a special Bruce Lee gold&silver coin collection.
What's the next suckers pick? A Chuck Norris version? I dont know what that tell's you ("GIANTs" ROTFLMAO), but to me nothing good, it's f*cking dead, never gonna touch it.
I know many intellecuals love to discuss over some JR stuff, sixty years ago, nice really nice and interessting in theory. But can that stuff really battle a Bruce Lee coin?
Another sign the bottom is either already in, or very close:
'but to me nothing good, it's f*cking dead, never gonna touch it.'
$5k an ounce within 2 years, mad times ahead.
Hope you're well AD.
Wonder what the Norcini "everything-is-priced-in" crowd is doing these days? Did they price in the unfolding Wolfe wave? All those front-running phonies beating their chest about gold is doomed and stocks are the place to be. Well, well, well.
He wrote a really stupid piece the other day about gold not doing well in deflation.
http://i.imgur.com/UsgcnYN.jpg
Something's up. I've long suspected it would be China that's executes Ben's 2002 speech.
That's where the gold is after all.
@Grumps
Since 2days I was wondering to say or not to say: You're a f****ng unbearable retard!!!1111. You're one of the worst I have ever encountered. Sorry @all, just cant bear with it any longer, needed to type it down.
@Gary
Thanks for asking. Yes, I am doing....hmmmm!!!??1111 dont know exactly. I am not sure if my retirement is doing me well :( Maybe it is some midlife crisis I am struggleing with, being without occupation, just thinking philosophical stuff. Again: Value does not exist (@Blondie can you hear me?), that's for sure....
In the meantime, not to spend too much time in the garden ;) I started a new development. Dont know if it brings me money (value?!???). If so, I will soon found a company in Gibraltar something like "John Galt Industries" (getting rid of the socialist tax assholes in the EU).
Greets, AD
Get a load of this.
http://www.pretivm.com/news/news-details/2015/Pretium-Resources-Inc-US540-Million-Construction-Financing-Production-Decision-for-Brucejack-Project/default.aspx
Blackstone, the Dark Lord of PE. What does it know?
The Financing is expected to close on or about September 18, 2015, the same day of the "RMB internationalization strategy seminar with Chinese gold notification"
http://www.cueb.edu.cn/xzhd_sy/70620.htm
Other tidbits:
"UK-China relations turn golden age"
http://www.kaixian.tv/gd/2015/0917/963788.html
3.6 trillion into nuclear weapons: China actually banned the use of foreign exchange dollar
http://blog.sina.com.cn/s/blog_7cb88ed60102w5dj.html
Grumps, the first Chinese link has an English 'button' but doesn't then produce the linked information.
The other two seem to be in Chinese only.
Is it a google translate job for those two?
Thanks.
Sorry, I use Chrome with the auto-translate function. Also if you put certain English phrases into the Google translate and then right-click the Chinese translation for google search, you will get much different search results than from an English search only.
Wish LIANG: RMB internationalization Thinking
http://roll.sohu.com/20150918/n421512119.shtml
"Nevertheless, non-monetary gold's role in international decline, why can not ignore it? I think there are reasons for such aspects. 1, the dominant currency has no function, but there is always the hidden money function, from the financial crisis can be seen growing. 2, gold shadow security functions at the International Monetary among very important, which is why the United States to date from gold monetization reasons. 3, gold is still an important international reserve asset, international monetary reserve assets which occupies an important proportion of the world's gold reserves also pimple pimple States. 4, gold as an international freely convertible currency to be possible to join SDR which, as the SDR basket of currencies among a component of the original four, the future may be used as a fifth gold SDR join them to go. Take gold as equivalent when the SDR had founded. 5, so far, in addition to gold yet to find a second super-sovereign currency. 1944 Keynes proposed the establishment of a supranational currency, 2012 Zhou Xiaochuan proposed the establishment of supranational currency, from the current world structure point of view, I do not see there is a new, second generation super-sovereign currency, and gold is currently the only one things become super-sovereign currency. In this sense, the value of gold also not be ignored. Third, the correct implementation of the process of internationalization of the Chinese renminbi gold strategy. In order to boost the internationalization of the RMB, with "along the way" strategy, China should correct implementation of the three gold strategy. First, vigorously implement the strategy of China's gold industry, the United Kingdom has been able to get to the gold standard, became the first overlord of the world strong world currency, because it is the country's gold production basically no, avoided it behind South Africa is such a the world's largest, ranking first in gold production do support. From the beginning of the United States in 1903, 50 years of gold production in the world, to date the United States is still an important production hardware power. Therefore, from the industrial point of view, to boost the internationalization of the RMB, the gold industry to vigorously engage in, how do not too much, we should vigorously develop. Especially in the "area all the way" strategy implementation process, "along the way" country has a very good strategic resources, we want to open up this one. Second, from the market point of view we should take to ponder, which should develop, the issue of how development issues."
China Commercial Banks and the global gold market under the background of internationalization of the RMB
http://yinhangye.juhangye.com/201509/news_3146678.html
"RMB internationalization and gold pricing:
Shanghai Gold Exchange has become the world's largest gold exchange-traded spot market, the Shanghai Futures Exchange, gold futures trading volume is rapidly approaching COMEX, for the construction of Shanghai international gold trading center of the foundation.
Gold Exchange, the international board will face trade zone with foreign institutional clients and establish a renminbi-denominated spot gold trading platform and settlement system, a move that will be the existing large offshore renminbi market has brought new investment channels, it is to promote the renminbi major initiatives the process of internationalization.
RMB internationalization and the impact of global commodity resource pricing, will be a significant feature of China's development over the next two years in the international monetary and financial sector. Gold as the most important monetary anchor, the pricing mechanism is far beyond the scope of ordinary commodity markets, has strategic significance.
Liberalization of the gold assets of institutional investors control
1, China's per capita gold holdings only about 5 grams, far behind the global average level of 23 grams. 2, subject to the regulation, China's institutional investors rarely hold gold assets. 3, from the experience of developed markets, the future gold will become an important part of the institutional asset allocation."
Post a Comment