The year 1752, that is. In 1752 David Hume published his
paper “On the balance of trade” presenting his theory about international trade
known as the ‘price>specie>flow
mechanism’. I have a theory to share with you about the ECB Eurosystem.
My theory is that Hume’s mechanism and the insights of the classical economists guided the Euro founding fathers’ in the design of two of the ECB’s most important currency management systems.
The two systems I’m referring to are the index called HICP
and TARGET2. The ECB uses HICP to assess its performance in maintaining an
average annual inflation rate of two (2) per cent. TARGET2 is the system
that facilitates the flow of money around the Eurozone. Hume’s mechanism is
usually discussed in terms of international trade but it is equally applicable
to regional trade. This post is about trade and other flows within
the Eurozone.My theory is that Hume’s mechanism and the insights of the classical economists guided the Euro founding fathers’ in the design of two of the ECB’s most important currency management systems.
Confining the discussion to one currency zone while we explore
this mechanism enables us to ignore some of the complications that need to be
addressed in looking at international trade between currency zones. So
when I rework part two of the series on gold and international trade settlement I’ll
concentrate on trade settlement between currency zones and let this post try to
explain the mechanism itself.
The main source I am drawing on for this post is a very
dense, scholarly book published in 1937 called “Studies
in the Theory of International Trade”. The writer was a
Professor of Economics at the University of Chicago named Jacob Viner (Here’s
a link to his bio.) In this book he discusses the work of the
classical economists on international free trade theory as well as the many
debates they were involved in.
Here is some background information for readers who are
unfamiliar with this mechanism. I style this mechanism as prices+>money>flow.
The expression ‘prices+’ is meant to convey that there are more factors
involved than prices alone. Jacob Viner discusses factors such as real costs,
relative demand, velocity, comparative advantage and so on. I replaced ‘specie’
with ‘money’ because this mechanism works with other types of money – not just
gold “specie” coins.
For this mechanism to deliver its benefits you simply need
to have the right conditions which are: (a)
The countries trading with each other must share a common currency; and (b) Minimal friction in the flow of goods
and money. In other words free trade and no capital controls or trade barriers to
interfere with the flows. The common currency could be like the Euro – a
currency union - but there are other ways to achieve the right conditions. If two
trading partners both accept gold specie as money (as they did in Hume’s proof)
then they are in one currency zone.
Now I need to emphasise a couple of important factoids about
this mechanism. It comes from thinkers who viewed trade as a human welfare
issue. To them trade was intrinsically a goods-for-goods and
exports-for-imports exercise not a goods-for-money exercise. (Wherever I use
the word ‘goods’ please read that as ‘goods and services’.) So we’ll leave the
exploration of the goods-for-money perspective for the trade settlement series
as well.
Hume’s mechanism didn’t increase overall trade between
countries and regions. It enabled the mix of the
most-demanded-goods available in each country to change. A flow of money was followed by a
flow of exports from Country A into its trading partner Country B. This temporarily increased the money supply
in Country B but the increased diversity of goods available to the citizens of
Country B would endure.
In David Ricardo’s words (as quoted by Viner) this resulted
in an increase in the “mass of commodities” and an increase in the
“sum of enjoyments.”
Ricardo also noted that people could increase their monetary savings instead if
they didn’t want to avail themselves of, say, cheaper goods by increasing their
consumption. Over time the prices+>money>flow mechanism rebalances the
volume of money in each country until the next trade disruption.
A closely related theory of the classical economists about
free trade was that it would tend to equalize the prices of the goods that were
traded. Arbitrage and competition would reduce price differentials to weed out
profit premiums and prices would more closely reflect actual cost differences
for transport, relative demand and so on.
In the second, final part of this post (with Professor
Viner’s help) we’ll try to connect the dots between TARGET2, HICP and the
prices+>money>flow mechanism.
No comments:
Post a Comment